Chapter 13
Imperfect compeTiTION: A game-theoretic approach
Boiling Down Chapter 13
The world seemed rather artificial in the market models of perfect competition and monopoly. It was a world of little variety and no complicating problems of interdependence, transportation costs, advertising, or product differentiation. We now must consider this more complex and realistic world.
The theory of imperfect competition explores strategies that help explain behavior where interdependence is present and firms must make assumptions about their opponent’s actions. Game theory is the tool used to explore many of these relationships. As in the prisoner's dilemma of Chapter 7 in your text, firms would be more profitable if they priced together above marginal cost than if they competed price down to marginal cost. Alternatively, the firm that cheated on the price agreement while the other firm cooperated would have the most profit possible. When the payoffs are such that a firm will be better off with one strategy no matter what the other firm does, a dominant strategy exists and will likely be followed. Table 13-2 in the text shows a duopoly situation where defecting is the dominant strategy. However, if additional price cuts would be damaging to both firms, the final outcome could be zero profits for both firms and the defecting strategy would not be dominant in the long run. In cases like cigarette advertising, the dominant strategy is to advertise even though it dissipates profit and leaves firms with less than they would have with a no-advertising strategy.
If both firms have a dominant strategy, a clear equilibrium exists. If only one firm has a dominant strategy and the other does not, an equilibrium still exists because the firm without the dominant strategy can predict what the other firm will do and choose its best action accordingly. This kind of equilibrium is called a Nash equilibrium.
When interaction among firms is ongoing, as it usually is, firms will be better off if they cooperate than if they defect, because if one defects the other feels compelled to defect and the payoff will be minimal for both. Guaranteeing cooperation is easiest when a defector can be punished in future transactions. One way to punish defectors is to promise to respond in kind each time defection occurs. If the promise is believed, a firm will lose over time if it defects, and so cooperation is likely. This strategy is called tit-for-tat and has been shown to effectively lead to cooperation in wartime circumstances as well as business situations. However, when more than two parties are involved in a game situation, tit-for-tat becomes difficult because it is hard to punish one defector without hurting cooperators
When action by players in a game is sequential, the first player will act based on her prediction of what the other player will do. If the most desirable action of the initial actor is undesirable to the opponent, but better than the result of retaliatory behavior, then the rational choice is not to retaliate. However, if retaliation would be a worst-case situation for the initiator, then certain retaliation would be the victim's best strategy. If doomsday actions can be guaranteed, the threat of doomsday is diminished. The example of the former USSR and U.S. foreign policy is an example of sequential strategy at work. If a doomsday device is installed that guarantees retaliation when a missile attack is launched, then the likelihood of an attack is diminished. In corporate strategy the same kind of automatic deterrence can convince competitors that a confrontation would be counterproductive. The Sears Tower case in the text is an example of this strategy in action. Competitors are not likely to enter a battle they know they will lose.
Oligopoly considers the market structure where only a few players are in the market game. They are highly interdependent since each firm is strongly influenced by what competitors do and must therefore make some assumption about how opponents will act and react in all market situations. Because of this interdependence, corporate strategy develops like a game based on anticipated behavior.
A Cournot duopolist assumes that the competitor will keep output constant even when faced with changes from its counterpart. This model develops a demand curve for a given firm by taking the difference between the total market demand and the output level of the competitor who maintains a constant output. This residual demand curve is then used to find the MC = MR profit-maximizing solution in the same manner that a monopolist would profit maximize. Cournot assumed MC to be zero for simplicity, so if the marginal revenue function is set equal to zero and solved for Q, an equation results that can be used to find the amount a firm should produce for all possible levels of an opponent's output. This equation is called a reaction curve.
In like manner, the reaction curve of the competitor can be derived. When the two reaction curves are plotted on a graph showing the ideal output for each firm after the opponent's quantity is given, an equilibrium can be seen where the two reaction curves intersect. The final output will be identical for each firm, and the total output will be one-third greater than the output that would have resulted from a single-price profit-maximizing monopolist.
Another attempt to explain duopoly behavior assumes that firms can alter price without changing a competitor's price decision. Given this assumption, it becomes desirable to price just below the competitor's price and sell to the entire market. Since both firms proceed in this fashion, they both end up pricing at marginal cost, if MC is constant, and the final outcome is the same as a perfectly competitive model. This Bertrand model seems similar to the Cournot model, in that it assumes a key decision of the competitor will remain constant no matter what a firm does, but its predictions are considerably different. However, both models have assumptions that appear unrealistic and the predictions of the models do not consistently match oligopoly outcomes.
The next step in exploring interdependence is to allow one of the duopolists to behave strategically. Stackelberg assumes that one of the Cournot firms, the Stackelberg leader, will anticipate that the other firm, the follower, will move along its reaction curve, thus changing the optimal output level for the initial firm. Instead of moving down its own reaction curve, the firm develops its own demand curve by substituting the opponent's reaction curve into the market demand curve in place of the opponent's quantity of output. Once the firm's own demand curve is specified, it is a simple matter to select the profit-maximizing price and quantity. This results in an equilibrium that has higher profits for the firm that behaved strategically. The model breaks down if both firms choose to behave strategically, in which case the second-guessing of a competitor's behavior is never-ending and therefore indeterminate. When compared with each other for efficiency and consumer benefit, the Bertrand model fares best since it results in the perfect competitive equilibrium point. The Stackelberg model rates second and Cournot third with the collusion shared monopoly model being the most harmful to consumers.
Economies of scale in oligopoly industries mean that the market may be too small to accommodate two firms at their lowest cost output. In this case the two firms sharing the market would have incentive to try to drive each other out and gain monopoly control. The fact that any aggressor may end up the loser makes aggressive price cutting less likely than a live-and-let-live strategy.
The first model of monopolistic competition developed is the Chamberlin model which focuses on the representative firm in a symmetrical market to show that product differentiation leads to higher price, excess capacity, and no economic profit. However, it does provide more variety in the marketplace because of the constant attempt for each of the many firms in the industry to differentiate their products from those of their competitors. These attempts to create special differentiated market niches can include product specification differences, spatial location differences or time variations.
The spatial model developed in this chapter weighs transportation costs against the increased costs of producing small batches in order to have more locations served. Having many smaller stores with higher per unit costs will be desirable only if the cost of getting to one large vendor more than dissipates the economies of scale that the larger vendor has. The optimal number of vendors occurs when the transportation savings from adding one more vendor exactly equals the extra cost per unit of production that results from having each vendor operate at a slightly smaller size.
It is a short jump from spatial considerations to time considerations. A plane ride involves the cost of flying and the cost of waiting for departure. The more often planes leave, the less waiting time is involved but the harder it is to fill the planes to capacity. As in the spatial cases, two costs are being weighed against each other. The ideal number of flights exists when the sum of these costs is minimized.
The value of this spatial model is apparent when one realizes that it can be applied to almost any case of product differentiation. The desire for variety must be constantly compared with the costs of differentiation. Wherever various product characteristics are possible, a tradeoff exists that cannot be ignored. Generic white shirts would be cheaper than shirts with 100 different colors and labels, but then people could not express their individuality. One grade of gasoline would be easier to produce, thus cheaper than four types, but then performance and economy lovers could not both be satisfied. If variety is the spice of life, then monopolistic models like the spatial model will be useful tools in analyzing how far product differentiation will go.
The cost of variety is borne more heavily by the rich than the poor because the rich have a higher demand for variety than do the poor. Vendors price the Cadillacs and exotic restaurant food higher relative to cost because they know that the desire for such differentiated goods is expressed mostly by the rich.
So far, it has been assumed that vendors respond to consumer demand for variation. This has been called the traditional sequence of markets. However, John Galbraith's "revised sequence" suggests that advertising is the vendors' way of programming consumers to feel demand for differentiated products. This programming is intended to develop product loyalty and enhance demand for a given firm's product. The flaw in the revised sequence is that consumers will buy only a product that pleases them. They will not likely be fooled twice if a product does not live up to its hype. Consequently, it serves little purpose to advertise a product that does not fit a perceived need in the consumer's market basket, especially in the area of experience-type goods. Thus, this revised sequence is weak, and, where it is effective, will work only briefly. It is likely that few vendors will spend great sums for a minimal, short-run impact. Only when the vendor is sure of success will a large advertising budgets be mobilized.
Chapter Outline
Important Terms
game theory oligopoly-duopoly dominant strategy collusion |
antitrust guidelines |
payoff matrix |
contestable markets |
prisoners dilemma |
spatial modeling |
sequential games |
product characteristics |
strategic entry deterrence |
revised sequence |
Cournot model |
traditional sequence |
residual demand curve |
firms that are perfectly symmetrical |
reaction function |
Chamberlin model |
Bertrand model |
DD and dd demand curves |
Stackelberg model |
|
A Case to Consider
1. Megan and Matt have recently recognized that the action of one of them significantly affects the business of the other. Therefore each has developed a strategy that takes the other person's output as given. Then the profit maximizing price and output are determined from the market that is left. This case is designed to help you find out where the computer market equilibrium will be, assuming that the market demand is P = 1,800 - Q, where Q is equal to the sum of the quantity produced by both Megan and Matt. If Megan believes that Matt will sell 500 computers per day, what is Megan's demand curve? (Answer in both numerical terms and with notation assuming that the demand curve notation is P = a - bQ and where Q = Qm + Qg represents the quantities of both Matt and Megan, respectively.)
2. What will Megan's marginal revenue curve be? (Again, use both notation and numerical forms.)
3. If Megan has constant marginal costs of 600 dollars per computer and acts as a Cournot duopolist, what will her output be if Matt keeps producing at 500 units?
4. Since Megan would have a different profit-maximizing price and quantity for each possible quantity of output produced by Matt, the equation showing her profit-maximizing quantity is called her reaction curve. What would that reaction curve be? (Hint: Derive it in the same way that Equation 13.3 is derived in the text, except that marginal cost is positive rather than zero. This equation should be in notational form.)
5. Sketch a graph below, with the quantity for Matt on the horizontal axis and the quantity for Megan on the vertical axis. Draw the reaction curve for Megan using the numbers of this case.
6. In a manner similar to question 4 above, derive Matt's reaction curve to Megan and plot it on the graph above.
7. If Matt develops a strategy like Megan's and they both act consistently on that strategy, what will the equilibrium price and quantity be for each vendor? (Hint: The quantity will occur where the two reaction curves intersect, and the price can then be read from the individual demand curves.)
8. What will happen in this market if Matt and Megan change their strategy and assume that the other one will not change price? Describe the process in words, and give a numerical price and quantity solution. Assume for this question that there are no fixed costs in computer vending. Use the same 600 dollar marginal computer cost that existed above.
9. If Matt and Megan secretly colluded to fix prices as if they were a profit-maximizing cartel, what would their price and joint output be? How much profit would each make?
Multiple-Choice Questions
8. When a deep recession hits an economy and an oligopoly industry like the auto industry, what happens to the reaction curves of these oligopoly firms?
a. They shift to the right.
b. They shift to the left.
c. They are unaffected by recession pressures.
d. They are effected but it is impossible to tell how they are effected because any outcome would be possible because of the high level of interdependence.
9. Which oligopoly model would be most desirable from the point of view of the consumer?
20. An island has a 100 mile road around its perimeter and there are 10 restaurants located equidistant from each other on the road. What is the average round trip mileage that each customer will have to travel for a restaurant meal? Assume the people are located equidistant from each other on the island road.
a. 10 miles
b. 5 miles
c. 2.5 miles
d. 20 miles
Problems
4. Figure 13.16 in your text shows the two cost functions that must be considered when the optimal number of restaurants is sought. Using a similar graph, sketch in the two cost functions that would need to be considered by an airline company that was trying to determine how many flights a day to make to a given city. One function will be the costs of flying the plane and its passengers. The other function will be the cost to passengers in waiting time. After sketching these costs, vertically sum them and show where the optimal number of flights will be. Make up your own numbers, but the general slopes of the functions will be the important part of this problem. Finally, if there were equations given for both of the functions you draw, how would you go about solving for the optimal number of flights? List the steps required and the equilibrium condition necessary for the optimal number of flights to be attained.
Number of flights
Thomas
David |
Top choice for a date |
Second choice for a date |
Top choice for a date |
A = 20 B = 0 |
A = 8 B = 18 |
Second choice for a date |
A = 18 B = 10 |
A = 15 B = 15 |
7. True or false: A Nash equilibrium will also be the most desirable point for the firms to be in. Explain.
answers to Questions for Chapter 13
Case Questions
Matt’s Reaction Curve
Quantity for Megan
600 1200
Multiple-Choice Questions
Problems
1. b) Yes, Nigeria cheats so the Saudis will cheat and neither have incentive to fix once they are in the cheating mode.
1. c) Nigeria would fix if they could be sure that the Saudis would follow.
2. a) Put Neil on the left and Laura on the top of a four quadrant matrix. Put an A‑ for each in the northwest cell, a B for each in the southeast cell, an A for Neil and a D for Laura in the southwest cell, and a D for Neil and an A for Laura in the northeast cell. The upper row shows Neil handing in a blank paper as does the first column for Laura.
2. b) Both Laura and Neil have a dominant strategy to cheat, and this is why the students always fail in their effort to get easy A’s in my class.
3. a) P = 50 _ QT
4. See the sketch labeled Problem 13-4 for a sketch of the optimal number of flights. The first step is to find the first derivatives of each of the two cost functions. That will tell you how fast the one cost is falling and how rapidly the other cost is rising. Then set the two derivatives equal to each other and solve for the number of flights. As long as one cost falls faster than the other cost is rising the total costs are falling. When the rising cost rises faster than the falling cost is falling the total costs are rising. Only when the two rates of change in cost are the same will total costs be minimized. Since the derivatives measure the rates of change in costs, setting them equal will be the equilibrium condition.
Assumption |
Quantity of A |
Quantity of B |
Price |
Profit of A |
Profit of B |
a |
|
|
|
|
|
b |
|
|
|
|
|
c |
|
|
|
|
|
d |
|
|
|
|
|
Bridgestone
Goodyear |
$100 |
$60 |
$100 |
F = 20: G = 36 |
F = 33: G = 10 |
$60 |
F = 12: G = 35 |
F = 11: G = 30 |
3. True or False If neither one of two interdependent firms in the same industry has a dominant strategy, then a Nash equilibrium cannot exist. Explain.
5. The revised sequence of J.K. Galbriath has considerable intuitive appeal, but may be lacking in real world applicability. Describe the concept briefly and explain why it may not be accurate.
Source: http://highered.mheducation.com/sites/dl/free/0073375942/695206/CH13new09.doc
Web site to visit: http://highered.mheducation.com
Author of the text: not indicated on the source document of the above text
If you are the author of the text above and you not agree to share your knowledge for teaching, research, scholarship (for fair use as indicated in the United States copyrigh low) please send us an e-mail and we will remove your text quickly. Fair use is a limitation and exception to the exclusive right granted by copyright law to the author of a creative work. In United States copyright law, fair use is a doctrine that permits limited use of copyrighted material without acquiring permission from the rights holders. Examples of fair use include commentary, search engines, criticism, news reporting, research, teaching, library archiving and scholarship. It provides for the legal, unlicensed citation or incorporation of copyrighted material in another author's work under a four-factor balancing test. (source: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Fair_use)
The information of medicine and health contained in the site are of a general nature and purpose which is purely informative and for this reason may not replace in any case, the council of a doctor or a qualified entity legally to the profession.
The following texts are the property of their respective authors and we thank them for giving us the opportunity to share for free to students, teachers and users of the Web their texts will used only for illustrative educational and scientific purposes only.
All the information in our site are given for nonprofit educational purposes
The information of medicine and health contained in the site are of a general nature and purpose which is purely informative and for this reason may not replace in any case, the council of a doctor or a qualified entity legally to the profession.
www.riassuntini.com